Closing the chapter on highly dynamic global trade
Notwithstanding larger temporary shocks, the rate of growth in global trade cannot permanently depart from that of global production. This is a logical necessity and an empirical fact (as it is argued in our Rue de la Banque). Reducing trade barriers, for example, increases the level of openness and growth in global trade as it transitions toward a new equilibrium. Following each shock, however, the trade-output elasticity, i.e., the ratio between trade and output growth rates, returns to equilibrium (1).
Over the past two decades, China has been the catalyst of such shocks. The emergence of China in the global economy and the fragmentation of GVCs are connected. GVCs were often developed by taking advantage of great opportunities in China to localize tasks that require intense labour and low or medium skills. Furthermore, trade liberalization improved and secured Chinese producers’ access to the global market, multinational firms also gained access to the Chinese market (particularly to intermediate goods with high added value). With China’s admission to the World Trade Organization in 2001, the supply of Chinese labour in the globally traded goods sector has put downward pressure on the price of manufactured goods (boosting the increased global demand for consumer electronics, for example; see chart 3 in our Rue de la Banque). At the same time, Chinese demand has contributed to a rise in the cost of raw materials, generating an increase in import expenditure of commodity producing countries (see post by Daniel Gros, 10/11/16 and speech given by J.H. Powell of the Federal Reserve System Board of Governors, 11/18/16).
Toward a normalization of China’s openness
Several factors combined to normalize China’s openness to the world: fewer opportunities abroad; higher wages; diversified supply and demand; and rebalancing of China’s growth model to domestic demand, including real appreciation of the exchange rate between 2005 and 2015. Given the production shift toward the services sector, China’s impact on prices has lessened or reversed.
Chart 2 shows that China’s export openness (red) has dropped sharply since 2007, while that of advanced economies (blue) and emerging-market economies (green) did not experience a similar drop. Evidence related to import openness is the same.