Eco Notepad

Carbon tax: a comparison of the impact in France and the rest of Europe

Published on 10 February 2021

Post n°203. How would the impact of a European carbon tax on the French economy differ from that in the rest of the EU? The medium-run impact on value added would be 20% lower in France than in the rest of the EU. This divergence would stem more from differences in the sectoral structure of the economy (the weight of those sectors most affected, inter-sectoral flows) than from differences in carbon intensity between homologous sectors.

Image Breakdown by sector of the impact on real value added in France and in the rest of the EU
Chart 1: Breakdown by sector of the impact on real value added in France and in the rest of the EU
Source: Authors' calculations.

Note: Medium-run impacts of a rise in the carbon price of EUR 50/ton, expressed as a % of value added in the region under consideration. The difference is in percentage points.

Economists consider a carbon tax to be a vital tool in the fight against climate change, as it can provide an incentive for economic actors – households and firms – to reduce their greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions.

This blog post examines the economic effects of a carbon tax under a theoretical scenario where, in order to meet the European Commission’s stated targets (55% reduction in emissions by 2030 compared with 1990 levels, and carbon neutrality by 2050), all European Union (EU) countries adopt a harmonised carbon tax regime over the next few years. It does not address the issue of the environmental efficiency of such a tax, or the policies that might be implemented to complement it (redistribution policy, support for green investments, etc.).

Drawing on a recent working paper, we show that the impact on the French economy would be smaller than in the rest of the EU. This can mainly be explained by differences in the sectoral structure of production.

A sectoral model of carbon taxation

We simulate the medium-run impact of an EU-wide rise in the carbon price of EUR 50/ton of CO2 equivalent, using a multi-sector model in which the countries are aggregated into three blocks: France, the rest of the EU and the rest of the world. The rise consists in a tax on fossil energy consumption (oil, coke), which is paid by households and firms, and a tax paid by firms on the GHG emissions generated directly by their activities, such as the methane produced by cattle farming. Thanks to its sectoral granularity, the model takes into account variations in the additional costs generated by the tax depending on the sector and its technological characteristics. The higher a sector’s carbon intensity – defined as the quantity of GHG emissions per euro produced – the higher the rate of tax it has to pay per euro produced. The tax paid by firms would amount to 0.6% of France’s value added (compared with 0.9% in the rest of the EU), but rates for individual sectors would range from 0.03% for financial, real estate and specialised activities, to 12.2% for agriculture. The tax paid by households would amount to 0.16% of consumption in France, compared with 0.22% in the rest of the EU. We assume that all tax proceeds are redistributed equally across all households.

The model explicitly reproduces the international production network at sector level, i.e. all global flows of intermediate and final consumption between productive sectors and households. As a result, it takes into account the interdependence between sectors and countries caused by global value chains in production processes: both the suppliers and customers of firms in taxed sectors are affected through this channel. Producers may also modify their choice of intermediate inputs to minimise their production costs in response to the tax – for example by reducing their fossil energy use in favour of electricity.

Chart 2 presents France’s sectoral structure in schematic form. It shows that certain sectors such as manufacturing, wholesale and retail trade, and administrative service activities have significant exchanges with other sectors. They are highly interconnected and are thus nodes in the propagation of the tax effects.

Image Diagram of the French economy’s production networks
Chart 2: Diagram of the French economy’s production networks
Source: Authors' calculations.

Note: The size of the red dots reflects the weight of each sector in value added, and the width of the blue lines reflects the amount of the main bilateral exchanges. Flows with foreign countries are not shown in the diagram to make it easier to read, but they are included in the model. ICT: information and communication technology

The impact of the tax is highly dependent on the sectoral structure of production

By construction, in our simulation, the tax rates applied to each sector depend on their respective GHG emissions. Thus, a sector that uses less carbon-intensive technologies will be less affected by the tax. For example, thanks to nuclear technology, the tax rate applied to France’s electricity production sector is half that applied to the same sector in the rest of the EU. As a result, its value added only declines by 0.6%, compared with a fall of 0.8% in the rest of the EU. However, its contribution to the aggregate impact is small, as shown in Chart 1a which provides a sectoral breakdown of the impacts in France and the rest of the EU.

By contrast, due to composition effects, sectors that are low-polluting but which account for a high share of aggregate value added are among the biggest contributors in both regions: financial, legal and real estate services, trade, health care and public administration account for 40% of the decline in value added, both in France and the rest of the EU. Unsurprisingly, the manufacturing industry, which generates more pollution and has a higher economic weight, especially in the rest of the EU, is the second biggest contributor to the fall in value added.

As well as being shaped by carbon intensity or by the economic weight of individual sectors, the impact of the tax is determined in a complex manner by the way in which it is propagated across national and international production networks (see Chart 2 for a simplified view of this for France): on the one hand it leads to a price rise which is then propagated downstream in value chains; on the other hand it triggers a fall in demand for intermediate inputs which is then propagated upstream. The extent of the propagation therefore depends on the size of the individual sectors, their relative positions in the production network, and the volume of bilateral inter-sectoral exchanges. Those sectors highest up in the network will be particularly affected, due to negative spillover effects that impact demand for their output. Mining and quarrying, as well as refined petroleum products – which is also affected directly by the tax on fossil fuel purchases – are among the worst-affected sectors.

A smaller impact in France than in the rest of the European Union

The rise in the carbon price in our scenario would reduce real value added in France by 0.8% compared with a decline of 1.0% in the rest of the EU – in other words, the aggregated impact in France would be 20% smaller.

Despite the differences between the two regions in terms of carbon intensity (higher for French households but lower on average for French firms than in the rest of the EU), this divergence mainly reflects differences in sectoral structure: even if the same tax rates were applied in both country blocks, there would still be a difference of 0.2 percentage point between the aggregate impact in France and that in the rest of the EU.

Due to composition effects, the sectors “oil, coke, mining and quarrying” and “manufacturing” account for more than half of the difference in impact between the two regions (see Chart 1b). They are among the sectors most affected by the tax, and have a higher economic weight in the rest of the EU than in France. Conversely, some sectors make a bigger contribution to the fall in value added in France than in the rest of the EU by virtue of their size: agriculture, public administration and defence, and administrative service activities. Aside from agriculture, however, these sectors are the least affected by the tax.

Conclusion

The analysis presented in this blog post illustrates the advantage of using a sectoral model to study the effects of a carbon price hike. It shows that, due to the structure of its economy, France is slightly better positioned than the rest of the EU to begin its climate transition using this tool. However, this study does not address the issue of how the impacts of a carbon tax may vary across households, or the need for a mechanism to redistribute tax proceeds in a gradual manner.

Updated on 25 July 2024